UNITED24 - Make a charitable donation in support of Ukraine!

Weapons of Mass Destruction (WMD)

11 February 2003

Text: Uncertainty on Iraq Limits Economic Growth, Greenspan Says

(Federal Reserve chairman warns against long-term budget deficits)
(5230)
The near-term outlook for the U.S. economy depends to a large degree
on the resolution of uncertainties over a possible war with Iraq,
Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan says.
Presenting February 11 his semiannual monetary policy report to
Congress, Greenspan gave cautiously optimistic assessment of the
potential of the U.S. economy to expand but said worries over the Iraq
situation dampens corporate willingness to spend.
"The heightening of geopolitical tensions has only added to the marked
uncertainties that have piled up over the past three years, creating
formidable barriers to new investment and thus to a resumption of
vigorous expansion of overall economic activity," the chief of the
U.S. central bank said before the Senate Banking Committee.
If the uncertainties diminish, "our more probable expectation,"
financial conditions should eventually facilitate more vigorous
business investment, which is essential for faster economic growth, he
said. Business investment also depends on market conditions and the
prospects for profits and cash flow, he added.
However, "various initiatives for conventional monetary and fiscal
stimulus will doubtless move higher on the policy agenda" if
constraints to expansion remain despite easing of risks related to the
Iraqi crisis, he said.
Greenspan suggested that Congress should construct the budget using an
accounting system that would "lay out more clearly the true costs and
benefits of changes to various taxes and outlay programs and
facilitate the development of broad budget strategy." But no matter
what accounting system is used, he said, budget discipline needs to be
reestablished "without delay," especially considering the pending
retirements of the baby boom generation, which he said will put a huge
burden on public pension and health care systems.
Absent budgetary rules placing caps on spending increases and
restricting any tax cuts that create budget deficits, the political
bias in favor of increasing deficits is likely to become entrenched,
Greenspan said.
"We are all too aware that government spending programs and tax
preferences can be easy to initiate or expand but extraordinarily
difficult to trim or shut down once constituencies develop that have a
stake in maintaining the status quo," he said.
Greenspan cautioned that restoring budget balance will require
discipline on both revenue and spending decisions but said the latter
"may prove the more difficult."
He said faster economic growth would help containing budget gaps but
would not likely provide the full solution to currently projected
long-term deficits.
"So, short of a major increase in immigration, economic growth cannot
be safely counted upon to eliminate deficits and the difficult choices
that will be required to restore fiscal discipline," Greenspan said.
In response to a question, he said he is not convinced that the
economy currently needs more economic stimulus.
President Bush has recently proposed sizeable tax cuts to accelerate
economic growth now and create favorable economic conditions in the
future. The plan was criticized by Democrats who said it would lead to
huge budget deficits in the future.
Following is the text of the testimony as prepared for delivery:
(begin text)
The Federal Reserve Board
Testimony of Chairman Alan Greenspan
Federal Reserve Board's semiannual monetary policy report to the
Congress
Before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, U.S.
Senate
February 11, 2003
Mr. Chairman and members of the committee, I am pleased this morning
to present the Federal Reserve's semiannual Monetary Policy Report to
the Congress. I will begin by reviewing the state of the U.S. economy
and the conduct of monetary policy and then turn to some key issues
related to the federal budget.
When I testified before this committee last July, I noted that, while
the growth of economic activity over the first half of the year had
been spurred importantly by a swing from rapid inventory drawdown to
modest inventory accumulation, that source of impetus would surely
wind down in subsequent quarters, as it did. We at the Federal Reserve
recognized that a strengthening of final sales was an essential
element of putting the expansion on a firm and sustainable track. To
support such a strengthening, monetary policy was set to continue its
accommodative stance.
In the event, final sales continued to grow only modestly, and
business outlays remained soft. Concerns about corporate governance,
which intensified for a time, were compounded over the late summer and
into the fall by growing geopolitical tensions. In particular, worries
about the situation in Iraq contributed to an appreciable increase in
oil prices. These uncertainties, coupled with ongoing concerns
surrounding macroeconomic prospects, heightened investors' perception
of risk and, perhaps, their aversion to such risk. Equity prices
weakened further, the expected volatility of equity prices rose to
unusually high levels, spreads on corporate debt and credit default
swaps deteriorated, and liquidity in corporate debt markets declined.
The economic data and the anecdotal information suggested that firms
were tightly limiting hiring and capital spending and keeping an
unusually short leash on inventories. With capital markets
inhospitable and commercial banks firming terms and standards on
business loans, corporations relied to an unusual extent on a drawdown
of their liquid assets rather than on borrowing to fund their limited
expenditures.
By early November, conditions in financial markets had firmed somewhat
on reports of improved corporate profitability. But on November 6,
with economic performance remaining subpar, the Federal Open Market
Committee chose to ease the stance of monetary policy, reducing the
federal funds rate 50 basis points, to 1-1/4 percent. We viewed that
action as insurance against the possibility that the still widespread
weakness would become entrenched. With inflation expectations well
contained, this additional monetary stimulus seemed to offer
worthwhile insurance against the threat of persistent economic
weakness and unwelcome substantial declines in inflation from already
low levels.
In the weeks that followed, financial market conditions continued to
improve, but only haltingly. The additional monetary stimulus and the
absence of further revelations of major corporate wrongdoing seemed to
provide some reassurance to investors. Equity prices rose, volatility
declined, risk spreads narrowed, and market liquidity increased,
albeit not to levels that might be associated with robust economic
conditions. At the same time, mounting concerns about geopolitical
risks and energy supplies, amplified by the turmoil in Venezuela, were
mirrored by the worrisome surge in oil prices, continued skittishness
in financial markets, and substantial uncertainty among businesses
about the outlook.
Partly as a result, growth of economic activity slowed markedly late
in the summer and in the fourth quarter, continuing the choppy pattern
that prevailed over the past year. According to the advance estimate,
real GDP [gross domestic product] expanded at an annual rate of only
3/4 percent last quarter after surging 4 percent in the third quarter.
Much of that deceleration reflected a falloff in the production of
motor vehicles from the near-record level that had been reached in the
third quarter when low financing rates and other incentive programs
sparked a jump in sales. The slowing in aggregate output also
reflected aggressive attempts by businesses more generally to ensure
that inventories remained under control. Thus far, those efforts have
proven successful in that business inventories, with only a few
exceptions, have stayed lean -- a circumstance that should help
support production this year. Indeed, after dropping back a bit in the
fall, manufacturing activity turned up in December, and reports from
purchasing managers suggest that improvement has continued into this
year. Excluding both the swings in auto and truck production and the
fluctuations in non-motor-vehicle inventories, economic activity has
been moving up in a considerably smoother fashion than has overall
real GDP: Final sales excluding motor vehicles are estimated to have
risen at a 2-1/4 percent annual rate in the fourth quarter after a
similar 1¾ percent advance in the previous quarter and an average of 2
percent in the first half.
Thus, apart from these quarterly fluctuations, the economy has largely
extended the broad patterns of performance that were evident at the
time of my July testimony. Most notably, output has continued to
expand, but only modestly. As previously, overall growth has
simultaneously been supported by relatively strong spending by
households and weighed down by weak expenditures by businesses.
Importantly, the favorable underlying trends in productivity have
continued; despite little change last quarter, output per hour in the
nonfarm business sector rose 3-3/4 percent over the four quarters of
2002, an impressive gain for a period of generally lackluster economic
performance. One consequence of the combination of sluggish output
growth and rapid productivity gains has been that the labor market has
remained quite soft. Employment turned down in the final months of
last year, and the unemployment rate moved up, but the report for
January was somewhat more encouraging.
Another consequence of the strong performance of productivity has been
its support of household incomes despite the softness of labor
markets. Those gains in income, combined with very low interest rates
and reduced taxes, have permitted relatively robust advances in
residential construction and household expenditures. Indeed,
residential construction activity moved up steadily over the year. And
despite large swings in sales, underlying demand for motor vehicles
appears to have been well maintained. Other consumer outlays, financed
partly by the large extraction of built-up equity in homes, have
continued to trend up. Most equity extraction -- reflecting the
realized capital gains on home sales -- usually occurs as a
consequence of house turnover. But during the past year, an almost
equal amount reflected the debt-financed cash-outs associated with an
unprecedented surge in mortgage refinancings. Such refinancing
activity is bound to contract at some point, as average interest rates
on outstanding home mortgages converge to interest rates on new
mortgages. However, fixed mortgage rates remain extraordinarily low,
and applications for refinancing are not far off their peaks. Simply
processing the backlog of earlier applications will take some time,
and this factor alone suggests that refinancing originations and
cash-outs will be significant at least through the early part of this
year.
To be sure, the mortgage debt of homeowners relative to their income
is high by historical norms. But as a consequence of low interest
rates, the servicing requirement for the mortgage debt of homeowners
relative to the corresponding disposable income of that group is well
below the high levels of the early 1990s. Moreover, owing to continued
large gains in residential real estate values, equity in homes has
continued to rise despite sizable debt-financed extractions. Adding in
the fixed costs associated with other financial obligations, such as
rental payments of tenants, consumer installment credit, and auto
leases, the total servicing costs faced by households relative to
their incomes are below previous peaks and do not appear to be a
significant cause for concern at this time. While household spending
has been reasonably vigorous, we have yet to see convincing signs of a
rebound in business outlays. After having fallen sharply over the
preceding two years, new orders for capital equipment stabilized and,
for some categories, turned up in nominal terms in 2002. Investment in
equipment and software is estimated to have risen at a 5 percent rate
in real terms in the fourth quarter and a subpar 3 percent over the
four quarters of the year.
However, the emergence of a sustained and broad-based pickup in
capital spending will almost surely require the resumption of
substantial gains in corporate profits. Profit margins apparently did
improve a bit last year, aided importantly by the strong growth in
labor productivity.
Of course, the path of capital investment will depend not only on
market conditions and the prospects for profits and cash flow but also
on the resolution of the uncertainties surrounding the business
outlook. Indeed, the heightening of geopolitical tensions has only
added to the marked uncertainties that have piled up over the past
three years, creating formidable barriers to new investment and thus
to a resumption of vigorous expansion of overall economic activity.
The intensification of geopolitical risks makes discerning the
economic path ahead especially difficult. If these uncertainties
diminish considerably in the near term, we should be able to tell far
better whether we are dealing with a business sector and an economy
poised to grow more rapidly -- our more probable expectation -- or one
that is still laboring under persisting strains and imbalances that
have been misidentified as transitory. Certainly, financial conditions
would not seem to impose a significant hurdle to a turnaround in
business spending. Yields on risk-free Treasury securities have
fallen, risk spreads are narrower on corporate bonds, premiums on
credit default swaps have retraced most of their summer spike, and
liquidity conditions have improved in capital markets. These factors,
if maintained, should eventually facilitate more-vigorous corporate
outlays.
If instead, contrary to our expectations, we find that, despite the
removal of the Iraq-related uncertainties, constraints to expansion
remain, various initiatives for conventional monetary and fiscal
stimulus will doubtless move higher on the policy agenda. But as part
of that process, the experience of recent years may be instructive. As
I have testified before this committee in the past, the most
significant lesson to be learned from recent American economic history
is arguably the importance of structural flexibility and the
resilience to economic shocks that it imparts.
I do not claim to be able to judge the relative importance of
conventional stimulus and increased economic flexibility to our
ability to weather the shocks of the past few years. But the improved
flexibility of our economy, no doubt, has played a key role. That
increased flexibility has been in part the result of the ongoing
success in liberalizing global trade, a quarter-century of bipartisan
deregulation that has significantly reduced rigidities in our markets
for energy, transportation, communication, and financial services,
and, of course, the dramatic gains in information technology that have
markedly enhanced the ability of businesses to address festering
economic imbalances before they inflict significant damage. This
improved ability has been facilitated further by the increasing
willingness of our workers to embrace innovation more generally.
It is reasonable to surmise that, not only have such measures
contributed significantly to the long-term growth potential of the
economy this past decade, they also have enhanced its short-term
resistance to recession. That said, we have too little history to
measure the extent to which increasing flexibility has boosted the
economy's potential and helped damp cyclical fluctuations in activity.
Even so, the benefits appear sufficiently large that we should be
placing special emphasis on searching for policies that will engender
still greater economic flexibility and dismantling policies that
contribute to unnecessary rigidity. The more flexible an economy, the
greater its ability to self-correct in response to inevitable, often
unanticipated, disturbances, thus reducing the size and consequences
of cyclical imbalances. Enhanced flexibility has the advantage of
adjustments being automatic and not having to rest on the initiatives
of policymakers, which often come too late or are based on highly
uncertain forecasts.
Policies intended to improve the flexibility of the economy seem to
fall outside the sphere of traditional monetary and fiscal policy. But
decisions on the structure of the tax system and spending programs
surely influence flexibility and thus can have major consequences for
both the cyclical performance and long-run growth potential of our
economy. Accordingly, in view of the major budget issues now
confronting the Congress and their potential implications for the
economy, I thought it appropriate to devote some of my remarks today
to fiscal policy. In that regard, I will not be emphasizing specific
spending or revenue programs. Rather, my focus will be on the goals
and process determining the budget and on the importance, despite our
increasing national security requirements, of regaining discipline in
that process. These views are my own and are not necessarily shared by
my colleagues at the Federal Reserve.
--
One notable feature of the budget landscape over the past half century
has been the limited movement in the ratio of unified budget outlays
to nominal GDP. Over the past five years, that ratio has averaged a
bit less than 19 percent, about where it was in the 1960s before it
moved up during the 1970s and 1980s. But that pattern of relative
stability over the longer term has masked a pronounced rise in the
share of spending committed to retirement, medical, and other
entitlement programs. Conversely, the share of spending that is
subject to the annual appropriations process, and thus that comes
under regular review by the Congress, has been shrinking. Such
so-called discretionary spending has fallen from two-thirds of total
outlays in the 1960s to one-third last year, with defense outlays
accounting for almost all of the decline.
The increase in the share of expenditures that is more or less on
automatic pilot has complicated the task of making fiscal policy by
effectively necessitating an extension of the budget horizon. The
Presidents' budgets through the 1960s and into the 1970s mainly
provided information for the upcoming fiscal year. The legislation in
1974 that established a new budget process and created the
Congressional Budget Office [CBO]required that organization to provide
five-year budget projections. And by the mid-1990s, CBO's projection
horizon had been pushed out to ten years. These longer time periods
and the associated budget projections, even granted their imprecision,
are useful steps toward allowing the Congress to balance budget
priorities sensibly in the context of a cash-based accounting
system.(1) But more can be done to clarify those priorities and
thereby enhance the discipline on the fiscal process.
A general difficulty concerns the very nature of the unified budget.
As a cash accounting system, it was adopted in 1968 to provide a
comprehensive measure of the funds that move in and out of federal
coffers. With a few modifications, it correctly measures the direct
effect of federal transactions on national saving. But a cash
accounting system is not designed to track new commitments and their
translation into future spending and borrowing. For budgets that are
largely discretionary, changes in forward commitments do not enter
significantly into budget deliberations, and hence the surplus or
deficit in the unified budget is a reasonably accurate indicator of
the stance of fiscal policy and its effect on saving. But as
longer-term commitments have come to dominate tax and spending
decisions, such cash accounting has been rendered progressively less
meaningful as the principal indicator of the state of our fiscal
affairs.
An accrual-based accounting system geared to the longer horizon could
be constructed with a reasonable amount of additional effort. In fact,
many of the inputs on the outlay side are already available. However,
estimates of revenue accruals are not well developed. These include
deferred taxes on retirement accounts that are taxable on withdrawal,
accrued taxes on unrealized capital gains, and corporate tax accruals.
An accrual system would allow us to keep better track of the
government's overall accrued obligations and deferred assets. Future
benefit obligations and taxes would be recognized as they are incurred
rather than when they are paid out by the government.(2)
Currently, accrued outlays very likely are much greater than those
calculated under the cash-based approach. Under full accrual
accounting, the social security program would be showing a substantial
deficit this year, rather than the surplus measured under our current
cash accounting regimen.(3) Indeed, under most reasonable sets of
actuarial assumptions, for social security benefits alone past
accruals cumulate to a liability that amounts to many trillions of
dollars. For the government as a whole, such liabilities are still
growing.
Estimating the liabilities implicit in social security is relatively
straightforward because that program has many of the characteristics
of a private defined-benefit retirement program. Projections of
Medicare outlays, however, are far more uncertain even though the rise
in the beneficiary populations is expected to be similar. The
likelihood of continued dramatic innovations in medical technology and
procedures combined with largely inelastic demand and a subsidized
third-party payment system engenders virtually open-ended potential
federal outlays unless constrained by law.(4) Liabilities for Medicare
are probably about the same order of magnitude as those for social
security, and as is the case for social security, the date is rapidly
approaching when those liabilities will be converted into cash
outlays.
Accrual-based accounts would lay out more clearly the true costs and
benefits of changes to various taxes and outlay programs and
facilitate the development of a broad budget strategy. In doing so,
these accounts should help shift the national dialogue and consensus
toward a more realistic view of the limits of our national resources
as we approach the next decade and focus attention on the necessity to
make difficult choices from among programs that, on a stand-alone
basis, appear very attractive.
Because the baby boomers have not yet started to retire in force and
accordingly the ratio of retirees to workers is still relatively low,
we are in the midst of a demographic lull. But short of an outsized
acceleration of productivity to well beyond the average pace of the
past seven years or a major expansion of immigration, the aging of the
population now in train will end this state of relative budget
tranquility in about a decade's time. It would be wise to address this
significant pending adjustment sooner rather than later. As the
President's just-released budget put it, "The longer the delay in
enacting reforms, the greater the danger, and the more drastic the
remedies will have to be."(5)
Accrual-based revenue and outlay projections, tied to a credible set
of economic assumptions, tax rates, and programmatic spend-out rates,
can provide important evidence on the long-term sustainability of the
overall budget and economic regimes under alternative scenarios.(6) Of
course, those projections, useful as they might prove to be, would
still be subject to enormous uncertainty. The ability of economists to
assess the effects of tax and spending programs is hindered by an
incomplete understanding of the forces influencing the economy.
It is not surprising, therefore, that much controversy over basic
questions surrounds the current debate over budget policy. Do budget
deficits and debt significantly affect interest rates and, hence,
economic activity? With political constraints on the size of
acceptable deficits, do tax cuts ultimately restrain spending
increases, and do spending increases limit tax cuts? To what extent do
tax increases inhibit investment and economic growth or, by raising
national saving, have the opposite effect? And to what extent does
government spending raise the growth of GDP, or is its effect offset
by a crowding out of private spending?
Substantial efforts are being made to develop analytical tools that,
one hopes, will enable us to answer such questions with greater
precision than we can now. Much progress has been made in ascertaining
the effects of certain policies, but many of the more critical
questions remain in dispute.
However, there should be little disagreement about the need to
reestablish budget discipline. The events of September 11 have placed
demands on our budgetary resources that were unanticipated a few years
ago. In addition, with defense outlays having fallen in recent years
to their smallest share of GDP since before World War II, the
restraint on overall spending from the downtrend in military outlays
has surely run its course -- and likely would have done so even
without the tragedy of September 11.
The CBO and the Office of Management and Budget recently released
updated budget projections that are sobering. These projections, in
conjunction with the looming demographic pressures, underscore the
urgency of extending the budget enforcement rules. To be sure, in the
end, it is policy, not process, that counts. But the statutory limits
on discretionary spending and the so-called PAYGO rules, which were
promulgated in the Budget Enforcement Act of 1990 and were backed by a
sixty-vote point of order in the Senate, served as useful tools for
controlling deficits through much of the 1990s. These rules expired in
the House last September and have been partly extended in the Senate
only through mid-April.
The Budget Enforcement Act was intended to address the problem of huge
unified deficits and was enacted in the context of a major effort to
bring the budget under control. In 1990, the possibility that
surpluses might emerge within the decade seemed remote indeed. When
they unexpectedly arrived, the problem that the budget control
measures were designed to address seemed to have been solved. Fiscal
discipline became a less pressing priority and was increasingly
abandoned.
To make the budget process more effective, some have suggested
amending the budget rules to increase their robustness against the
designation of certain spending items as "emergency" and hence not
subject to the caps. Others have proposed mechanisms, such as
statutory triggers and sunsets on legislation, that would allow the
Congress to make mid-course corrections more easily if budget
projections go off-track -- as they invariably will. These ideas are
helpful and they could strengthen the basic structure established a
decade ago. But, more important, a budget framework along the lines of
the one that provided significant and effective discipline in the past
needs, in my judgment, to be reinstated without delay.
I am concerned that, should the enforcement mechanisms governing the
budget process not be restored, the resulting lack of clear direction
and constructive goals would allow the inbuilt political bias in favor
of growing budget deficits to again become entrenched. We are all too
aware that government spending programs and tax preferences can be
easy to initiate or expand but extraordinarily difficult to trim or
shut down once constituencies develop that have a stake in maintaining
the status quo.
In the Congress's review of the mechanisms governing the budget
process, you may want to reconsider whether the statutory limit on the
public debt is a useful device. As a matter of arithmetic, the debt
ceiling is either redundant or inconsistent with the paths of revenues
and outlays you specify when you legislate a budget.
In addition, a technical correction in the procedure used to tie
indexed benefits and individual income tax brackets to changes in "the
cost of living" as required by law is long overdue. As you may be
aware, the Bureau of Labor Statistics has recently introduced a new
price index -- the so-called chained CPI [consumer price index]. The
new index is based on the same underlying data as is the official CPI
, but it combines the individual prices in a way that better measures
changes in the cost of living. In particular, the chained CPI captures
more fully than does the official CPI the way that consumers alter the
mix of their expenditures in response to changes in relative prices.
Because it appears to offer a more accurate measure of the true cost
of living -- the statutory intent -- the chained CPI would be a more
suitable series for the indexation of federal programs. Had such
indexing been in place during the past decade, the fiscal 2002 deficit
would have been $40 billion [$40,000 million] smaller, all else being
equal.
At the present time, there seems to be a large and growing
constituency for holding down the deficit, but I sense less appetite
to do what is required to achieve that outcome. Reestablishing budget
balance will require discipline on both revenue and spending actions,
but restraint on spending may prove the more difficult. Tax cuts are
limited by the need for the federal government to fund a basic level
of services -- for example, national defense. No such binding limits
constrain spending. If spending growth were to outpace nominal GDP,
maintaining budget balance would necessitate progressively higher tax
rates that would eventually inhibit the growth in the revenue base on
which those rates are imposed. Deficits, possibly ever widening, would
be the inevitable outcome.
Faster economic growth, doubtless, would make deficits far easier to
contain. But faster economic growth alone is not likely to be the full
solution to currently projected long-term deficits. To be sure,
underlying productivity has accelerated considerably in recent years.
Nevertheless, to assume that productivity can continue to accelerate
to rates well above the current underlying pace would be a stretch,
even for our very dynamic economy.(7) So, short of a major increase in
immigration, economic growth cannot be safely counted upon to
eliminate deficits and the difficult choices that will be required to
restore fiscal discipline.
By the same token, in setting budget priorities and policies,
attention must be paid to the attendant consequences for the real
economy. Achieving budget balance, for example, through actions that
hinder economic growth is scarcely a measure of success. We need to
develop policies that increase the real resources that will be
available to meet our longer-run needs. The greater the resources
available -- that is, the greater the output of goods and services
produced by our economy -- the easier will be providing real benefits
to retirees in coming decades without unduly restraining the
consumption of workers.
--
These are challenging times for all policymakers. Considerable
uncertainties surround the economic outlook, especially in the period
immediately ahead. But the economy has shown remarkable resilience in
the face of a succession of substantial blows. Critical to our
nation's performance over the past few years has been the flexibility
exhibited by our market-driven economy and its ability to generate
substantial increases in productivity. Going forward, these same
characteristics, in concert with sound economic policies, should help
to foster a return to vigorous growth of the U.S. economy to the
benefit of all our citizens.
Footnotes
(1) Unfortunately, they are incomplete steps because even a ten-year
horizon ends just as the baby boom generation is beginning to retire
and the huge pressures on social security and especially Medicare are
about to show through.
(2) In particular, a full set of accrual accounts would give the
Congress, for the first time in usable form, an aggregate tabulation
of federal commitments under current law, with various schedules of
the translation of those commitments into receipts and cash payouts.
(3) However, accrued outlays should exhibit far less deterioration
than the unified budget outlays when the baby boomers retire because
the appreciable rise in benefits that is projected to cause spending
to balloon after 2010 will have been accrued in earlier years.
(4) Constraining these outlays by any mechanism other than prices will
involve some form of rationing -- an approach that in the past has not
been popular in the United States.
(5) Office of Management and Budget, Budget of the United States
Government, Fiscal Year 2004, Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government
Printing Office, p. 32.
(6) In general, fiscal systems are presumed stable if the ratio of
debt in the hands of the public to nominal GDP (a proxy for the
revenue base) is itself stable. A rapidly rising ratio of debt to GDP,
for example, implies an ever-increasing and possibly accelerating
ratio of interest payments to the revenue base. Conversely, once debt
has fallen to zero, budget surpluses generally require the
accumulation of private assets, an undesirable policy in the judgment
of many.
(7) In fact, we will need some further acceleration of productivity
just to offset the inevitable decline in net labor force, and
associated overall economic, growth as the baby boomers retire.
(end text)
(Distributed by the Office of International Information Programs, U.S.
Department of State. Web site: http://usinfo.state.gov)



NEWSLETTER
Join the GlobalSecurity.org mailing list